Moreover, as this paper will explain, this process of change is consistent with the propositions of the literature on organizational learning (Haas, 2000; Haas & Haas, 1995; Siebenhüner, 2008; Siebenhüner & Arnold, 2007). In the 1980s, different prominent IOs such as UNESCO, the World Bank (WB), the Inter-American Development Bank (IADB), shifted from a strong emphasis on vocational secondary education to a preference for basic schooling (Benavot, 1983). This shift emerged as a result of new knowledge generated by cost-benefit assessments of vocational secondary education that revealed this kind of training as less efficient compared to basic schooling (Heyneman, 1987; Middleton, 1988; Psacharopoulos & Loxley, 1985). Later in the 2000s, secondary education was brought back into the IOs agenda due to criticism towards the pitfalls of cost-benefit analysis and a new understanding of the non-economic benefits of secondary education (Heyneman, 1995). Nonetheless, this time the vocationalization of secondary education was downplayed (The World Bank, 2005; UNESCO, 2005; UNESCO/OREALC, 2002). Learning literature however, pays little attention to the diffusion of the new ideas of IOs. …show more content…
In contrast, diffusion theories explain how IOs disseminate their beliefs by coercive and non-coercive means, persuading states to follow an idea that is finally internalized by different societies (Finnemore, 1993; H. D. Meyer & Rowan, 2006; J. W. Meyer, 1977). Although these theories accept that a contentious process emerges when transnational actors challenge existing norms (Finnemore, 1998; Keck & Sikkink, 1999), this scholarship often assumes that once the new norm becomes globally accepted, states ultimately tend to take it for granted and emulate it. In this way, these theories overlook political contestation at the domestic level and do not explain what happens when a new globally accepted standard arrives at a domestic setting and is prepared by a domestic organization for its adoption (Campbell, 2004). This paper addresses this gap and contends that learning in IOs does not necessarily lead to an effective diffusion and adoption of new norms. Instead, when this learning involves a radical change in the beliefs and behavior of the IOs, the diffusion of new ideas may be constrained by past global norms that have produced or promoted increasing returns at domestic level, making policy change difficult. In this way, the influence of IOs in domestic policymaking becomes ineffective. This argument is illustrated by the analysis of the learning process of the WB related to secondary education and its effects in Colombian secondary education policy. This case presents a puzzle for learning and diffusion theories. On